Co-ops-- cooperative
economic enterprises-- have been embraced by significant groups of
people at different times and places. Their attraction precedes the
heyday of industrial capitalism by offering a means to consolidate small
producers and take advantage of economies of scale, shared
risk, and common gain.
At the advent of the
industrial era, cooperatives were one of many competing solutions offered to
ameliorate the plight of the emerging proletariat. Social engineers
like Robert Owen experimented with cooperative enterprises and
communities.
In the era of mass
socialist parties and socialist construction, cooperatives were
considered as intermediate steps to make the transition from feudal
agrarian production towards socialist relations of production.
Under the capitalist mode
of production, co-ops have filled both employment and consumption
niches deferred by large scale capitalist production. Economic
activities offering insufficient profitability or growth have become
targets for cooperative enterprise.
In theory, cooperatives
may offer advantages to both workers and consumers. Workers are
thought to benefit because the profits that are expropriated by
non-workers in the capitalist mode of production are shared by the
workforce in a cooperative enterprise (less the present and anticipated
operating expenses and investments, of course). Many argue as well that the working
conditions are necessarily improved since workplace decisions are
arrived at democratically absent the lash associated with the
profit-mania of alienated ownership (though little attention is paid
to the consequences for productivity and competitiveness against
capitalist enterprises).
Consumers are said to
benefit when they collectively appropriate the retail functions
normally assumed by privately owned, profit-driven outlets. Benefit
comes, on this view, by purchasing from wholesale suppliers,
collectively meeting the labor requirements of distribution, and
enjoying the cost-savings from avoiding a product markup (little
attention is paid to limitations on participation dictated by class,
race, or gender; the wholesale quantity discounts enjoyed by
capitalist chains are also conveniently overlooked).
A case can also be made
for the cooperator's dedication to quality, safety, and health-
promotion.
In reality, cooperatives
in the US are largely indistinguishable from small businesses. Like
small private businesses, they employ few people and rely heavily
upon “sweat equity” for capitalization. Like other small
businesses, US cooperatives operate on the periphery of the US
economy, apart from the huge monopoly capitalist firms in
manufacturing, service, and finance.
Cooperatives
as a Political Program
Since
the demise of the Soviet Union and Eastern European socialism, many
on the US Left have rummaged for a new approach to the inequalities
and injustices that accompany capitalism. Where more than a decade
of anti-Communist purges had wrung nearly all vestiges of socialist
sympathy from the US psyche, the fall of the ludicrously-named “Iron
Curtain” found Leftists further distancing themselves from Marxian
socialism. Hastily interning the idea of socialism, they reached for
other answers.
It is unclear whether this retreat was actually a search
for a different anti-capitalist path or, in reality, grasping an opportunity to
say farewell to socialism.
In
recent years, several Leftists, “neo-Marxists”, or fallen
Marxists have advocated cooperatives as an anti-capitalist program.
Leading advocates include the Dollars and Sense
collective centered around the University of Massachusetts, Amherst,
GEO (Grassroots Economic Organizing), Professor Gar Alperovitz, Labor
Notes, United Steel Workers of America, and media
Marxist-du-jour, Professor Richard Wolff. Some are organizing around
the idea of a “New Economy” or a “Solidarity Economy”, with
cooperative enterprises as a centerpiece.
Now
coops are not foreign to Marxist theory. After World War I, the
Italian government sought to transfer ownership of unused land from
big estates, latifondi, on to peasants, especially veterans.
As much as 800,000 hectares were thus passed on to poor peasants.
Through this process and land seizures, the number of smallholders
increased dramatically. Socialists and Communists urged the
consolidation of these holdings into collectives, agricultural
cooperatives. Certainly more than 150,000 hectares ended up in
cooperatives. In those circumstances, the rationale was to increase
the productivity, to save the costs, to enhance the efficiency of
peasant agriculture in order to compete with the large private
estates. Cooperatives were not seen as an alternative to socialism,
but a rational step away from near feudal production relations toward
socialism, a transitional stage.
Likewise,
in the early years of the Soviet Union, Communists sought to improve
small-scale peasant production by organizing the countryside into
collective farms, producers' cooperatives. They saw cooperative
arrangements as rationalizing production and, therefore, freeing
millions from the tedium and grind of subsistence farming and
integrating them into industrial production. Through mechanization
and division of labor, they expected efficiency and productivity to
grow dramatically, speeding development and paving the way for
socialism.
Again,
cooperative enterprises counted as an intermediary for moving towards
socialist relations of production. Thus, Marxists see the
organization of cooperatives as a historically useful bridge between
rural backwardness and socialism.
But
modern day proponents of cooperatives see them differently.
“The
'evolutionary reconstructive' approach is a form of change different
not only from traditional reform, but different, too, from
traditional theories of 'revolution'” says Gar Alperovitz of
cooperatives and other elements of the “Solidarity Economy” (America beyond Capitalism, Dollars and Sense, Nov/Dec, 2011).
Like most proponents, Alperovitz sees cooperatives as pioneering a
“third way” between liberal reformism and socialist revolution.
However, a minority of advocates (Bowman and Stone, “How Coops
can Change the World”, D&S, Sept/Oct, 1998, for
example) see cooperatives as the “best first step towards that goal
[of a planned, democratic world economy]. They suggest that the
correct road is through “spreading workplace democracy” and on to
socialism.
Whether
postured as a “third way” or a step towards socialism, it is
difficult to get a clear picture of the extent and success of the
cooperative movement; it is equally challenging to gather a sense of
how it is suppose to function in a capitalist economy.
As
for numbers, Alperovitz (“America beyond Capitalism”, D&S,
Nov/Dec, 2011) muddies the waters by citing the numbers of
“community development corporations” and “non-profits”
(Alperovitz, 2011) as somehow strengthening the case for
cooperatives. The fact that community development corporations have
wrested control of neighborhoods from old-guard community and
neighborhood groups and embraced developers and gentrification causes
him no distress. Of course “non-profits” count as an even more
dubious expression of a solidarity economy. In a city like
Pittsburgh, PA, mega-non-profits remove 40% of the assessed property from
the tax rolls. These non-profits not only evade taxes, but divide enormous
“surpluses” among super-salaried executives. They beggar funding
from tax shelter trusts and endowment funds, completing the circle of
wink-and-a-nod tax evasion. Of course there are, as well, thousands
of “non-profits” that pursue noble goals and operate on a
shoestring.
Alperovitz
alludes to credit unions as perhaps sharing the spirit of cooperation
without noting the steady evolution of these once “third way”
institutions towards a capitalist business model. Insurance companies
also share this evolution, but they are too far down this path of
transition to capitalist enterprise to be credibly cited by
Alperovitz.
Alperovitz
leaves us with “...11,000 other businesses that are owned in whole
or part by their employees.” In this slippery total of whole or
partial worker ownership are included ESOPs-- Employee Stock
Ownership Programs, a touted solution to the plant closing surge that
ripped through the Midwest in the 1980s. Alperovitz pressed
vigorously for ESOPs in the steel industry in the 1980s as he does
cooperatives today. When asked to sum up their track record, one
sympathetic consultant, when pressed, said: “I don't think its been
a real good record of success. Some have actually failed...” (Mike
Locker, “Democracy in Steel?”, D&S, Sept/Oct,
1998). But we get no firm number for cooperatives in the US.
Another
advocacy group for cooperatives gave a more candid picture of the
cooperative movement in the Sept/Oct, 1998 issue of Dollars and
Sense (“ESOPS and Coops”). A study by the Southern
Appalachian Cooperative Organization claimed that there were 154
worker-owned cooperatives employing 6,545 members in the US. In sixty
percent of the 154, all workers were owners. Median annual sales were
$500,000 and 75 percent had 50 or fewer workers. Twenty-nine percent
of the coops were retail, twenty-eight percent were small
manufacturing, and twenty-three per cent food related businesses.
Interestingly,
the same article claims that there were approximately 11,000 ESOPs in
1988 (source: National Center of Employee Ownership). If we take
Alperovitz's 2011 claim seriously, there has been little growth in
the ensuing thirteen years of “...businesses that are owned in
whole or part by their employees...”.
From
this profile, we can conclude that cooperatives in the US are
essentially small businesses accounting for a tiny portion of the
tens of millions of firms employing less than 50 employees. As such,
they compete against the small service sector and niche manufacturing
businesses that operate on the periphery of monopoly capitalism.
Insofar as they pose a threat to capitalism, they only threaten the
other small-scale and family owned businesses that struggle against
the tide of price cutting, media marketing, and heavy promotion
generated by monopoly chains and low-wage production. They share the
lack of capital and leverage with their private sector counterparts.
Cooperatives swim against the tide of monopolization and acquisition
that have virtually destroyed the mom and pop store and the
neighborhood business.
Some
of the more clear-headed advocates acknowledge this reality. Betsy
Bowman and Bob Stone concede the point: “...Marx argued in 1864
that capitalists' political power would counteract any gains that
coops might make. This has proven true! When capitalists have felt
threatened by cooperatives, they have conducted economic war against
coops by smear campaigns, supplier boycotts, sabotage, and,
especially, denying credit to them.” (Bowman and Stone, D&S,
Sept/Oct, 1998).
Mondragon
Until
recently, cooperators and their advocates had one very large arrow in
their quiver.
When
pressed on the apparent weakness of cooperatives as an
anti-capitalist strategy, they would counter loudly: “Mondragon!”.
This
large-scale network of over 100 cooperative enterprises based in
Spain seemed to defy the criticisms of the cooperative alternative.
With 80,000 or more worker-owners, billions of Euros in assets and 14
billion Euros in revenue last year, Mondragon was the shining star of
the cooperative movement, the lodestone for the advocates of the global cooperative
program.
But
then in October, appliance maker Fagor Electrodomesticos, one of
Mondragon's key cooperatives, closed with over a billion dollars of
debt and putting 5500 people out of work. Worker-employees lost their
savings invested in the firm. Mondragon's largest cooperative, the
supermarket group Eroski, also owes creditors 2.5 billion Euros.
Because the network is so interlocked, these setbacks pose long term
threats to the entire system. As one worker, Juan Antonio Talledo, is
quoted in The Wall Street Journal (“Recession
Frays Ties at Spain's Co-ops”,
December 26, 2013):
“This is our Lehman moment.”
It
is indeed a “Lehman moment”. And like the Lehman Bros banking
meltdown in September of 2008, it makes a Lehman-like point. Large
scale enterprises, even of the size of Mondragon and organized on a
cooperative basis, are susceptible to the high winds of global
capitalist crisis. Cooperative organization offers no immunity to the
systemic problems that face all enterprises in a capitalist
environment. That is why a cooperative solution cannot constitute a
viable alternative to capitalism. That is why an island of
worker-ownership surrounded by a violent sea of capitalism is
unsustainable.
The
failures at Mondragon have sent advocates to the wood shed (see
www.geonewsletter.org).
Leading theoretical light, Gar Alperovitz, has written in response to
the Mondragon blues: “Mondragón's primary emphasis has been on
effective and efficient competition. But what do you do when you are
up against a global economic recession, on the one hand, or radical
cost challenges from Chinese and other low-cost producers, on the
other?”
What
do you do? Shouldn't someone have thought of that before they offered
a road map towards a “third way”? Are “global economic
recessions” uncommon? Is low cost production new? And blaming the
Chinese is simply unprincipled scapegoating.
Alperovitz
goes on: “The question of interest, however - and especially to the
degree we begin to face the question of what to do about larger
industry - is whether trusting in open market competition is a
sufficient answer to the problem of longer-term systemic design.”
Clear away the verbal foliage and Alperovitz is admitting that he
never anticipated that open market competition would snag Mondragon.
Did he think that Fagor sold appliances outside of the market? Did he
think that Mondragon somehow got a free pass in global competition?
Of
course the big losers are the workers who have lost their jobs and
savings. It would be mistaken to blame the earnest organizers or
idealistic cooperators who sincerely sought to make a better, more
socially just workplace. They gambled on a project and lost. Of
course social justice should not be a gamble.
The
same sympathy cannot be shown for those continuing to tout
cooperatives as an alternative to capitalism. If you want to open
small businesses (organized as cooperatives), be my guest! But please
don't tell me and others that it's somehow a path beyond capitalism.
Comrades
and friends: It's impossible to be anti-capitalist without being
pro-socialist!
Zoltan
Zigedy
10 comments:
Here in Cuba cooperatives are expanding all the time. The Cuban media regularly reports the expansion of cooperatives into areas which previously were state-owned.
The state simply cannot provide for every cup of coffee or sandwich made outside the home.
Furthermore, here in Cuba it´s been shown that state enterprises are subject to significant corruption. Workers steal from enterprises which belong to the state since they often see the state as something remote from themselves invidually.
Cooperatives are an advance over that in that workers, who know all the tricks about how to steal from the state can, hopefully, prevent one another from stealing because they know that they are, REALLY, stealing from each other.
Cooperatives are no solution to all problems in all times and places, but they shouldn´t be rejected for all times and places, either.
Thanks,
Walter Lippmann
Havana, Cuba
https://groups.yahoo.com/neo/groups/CubaNews/info
Here in Cuba, new cooperatives are opening every day.
It´s fine for you to warn against illusions in capitalism, but don´t throw the baby out with the bathwater.
Here in Cuba cooperatives are being organized as a way to address problems which state-owned enterprises haven´t been able to solve.
Don´t go overboard in your opposition to cooperatives.
Thanks,
Walter Lippmann
Havana, Cuba
https://groups.yahoo.com/neo/groups/CubaNews-
ZZ, you're setting up a straw man. Some cooperativists may have utopian 'third way' ideas, nor as any overall 'cure for capitalism.'
But most of us who argue for them see them as one more arrow in our quiver or tools to secure 'strong points' (Lenin's term) in a 'war of position' (Gramsci's term) with capital, along with unions, community groups, evening classes, political groups and so on. No one tactic is going to get you to a new order. But all of our arrows, taken together and fired appropriately, may get us over the top.
As for Mondragon, the fact that Fagor's 'white goods' arm was in trouble for some time was known to us. As with any network of businesses, even those owned entirely by workers, some will go under while others will be created. The test for MCC will be in its ability to transfer the Fagor worker-owners to one of the other 120 or so coops they have, or to design new ones.
In the US the small business failure rate is about 75%. In MCC's 50 year history, less than a dozen of the 120 or so have failed.
Not a bad comparison at all.
Walter is a welcome commentator on my blog. He is the indefatigable editor of CubaNews which provides the broadest and deepest coverage of news about the first socialist state of the Americas. He recently celebrated his 70th birthday in Havana, along with some unusually chilly weather!
Regarding Walter's comments, I make no reference to contemporary cooperatives in socialist states. My target is narrow: those who project cooperatives as an alternative to capitalism, as a road "beyond" US capitalism.
Worker-owned cooperatives in a socialist state are-- if they are truly worker-owned-- a form of social and not private ownership. They may inject the element of competition which my prove to be problematic.
Carl is a long-time advocate for cooperatives.
I combed through his comment and failed to find the dreaded s-word, "socialism". How does one reference Lenin and Gramsci without referencing the cause to which they devoted their life (literally, in the case of Gramsci)?
Is socialism the "new order" that Davidson desires? Or more small businesses? Or something else?
If Mondragon is best compared to small businesses, are we going to ride small businesses "over the top" (where ever that is)?
It's not a "straw man" that I'm chasing in my post; it's a shadow...
You missed the main title to my book on MCC and other aspects of the green and solidarity economies:
NEW PATHS TO SOCIALISM
http://www.lulu.com/us/en/shop/carl-davidson/new-paths-to-socialism/paperback/product-15998001.html
On the points from Davidson, Mr. Socialism-Will-Take-Centuries:
A trade union is a "strong point" for socialism to the degree that its leaders and activists help workers wage class struggle. Cooperatives in general do no such thing, and a good number of them are based on explicit visions of prospering without class struggle. Cooperatives might teach the staff how to do business and how investors allocate credit for maximum profit -- useful lessons for aspiring capitalists, but nothing that passes beyond economism to socialism.
Davidson is bipolar about Mondragon. On one hand, he claims that he and the leaders of Mondragon knew "for some time" that its Fagor appliance unit was hemorrhaging cash. What foresight! On the other hand, he tries to buy time against communist judgment of Mondragon by saying the test "will be" whether it finds profitable employment for Fagor workers elsewhere in the conglomerate. That is not much comfort to Fagor employees, who need to know now where they will get an income.
@Charles Andrews:
Actually, socialism can be achieved rather quickly, given political will and organization. It's the classless society of communism likely to take a century or two, especially on a global scale.
You think of Mondragon way too narrowly. Many within it see themselves as developing the economic base for an independent and socialist Euskadi.
Yes, we were told of Fagor's troubles, not only because of the shrinkage of the European housing markets, and hence markets for their 'white goods,' but also because of competition from China, who were approaching their levels of quality in the same goods sector. Their solution? Innovation in developing new coops with new products in new industries, mainly photovoltaics, health care, and robotics, to name a few.
The Fagor worker-owners do have a MCC-supplied cushion to ease the transition. It's called Lagun Aro, the second-degree worker-owned coop that provides their social insurance to see them through these difficulties.
Trade unions can help workers in class struggle to raise their wages and improve their conditions. MCC has a wider task, serving as a school whereby workers can learn first hand how they can be masters of their factories and their communities, without any need for capitalists, and to retain the surplus for the workers to develop as they see fit.
If you can't see how that aids us in a 'war of position,' you lack imagination.
In any case, MCC is only one piece of a puzzle, but a useful one. They inspired the workers of the former Republic Windows factory in Chicago to occupy it, and fight to take it over, now a New Era windows, owned by the workers. Was that not a part of class struggle too? Or should they have simply contented themselves with a better severance package.
Davidson assuring social democrats about "socialism" in 2009:
"...a protracted transition, over hundreds of years, to a future classless society where exploiting class privileges are abolished." The full document reeks of implied peaceful transition.
Davidson here, bowing and weaving:
"Socialism can be achieved rather quickly, given political will and organization. It's the classless society of communism likely to take a century or two, especially on a global scale."
Just will and organization? Is this before revolution, during a revolutionary moment as in 1917, or after? Generally, revolution disappears when Davidson talks about socialism.
"Many within Mondragon see themselves as developing the economic base for an independent and socialist Euskadi."
Let's take a word that simply means the Basque autonomous region of Spain and try to make readers think it is a vision of ... something.
As for Mondragon: "Yes, we were told of Fagor's troubles... also because of competition from China, who were approaching their levels of quality in the same goods sector. Their solution? Innovation in developing new coops with new products in new industries, mainly photovoltaics, health care, and robotics, to name a few."
The "solution" of climbing up the value-added ladder, going even more high tech, comes right from capitalist ideologues. For two or three decades they have promoted this drivel as the way to revive prosperity in the U.S., admonishing workers that they must scramble to wind up in the technical top ten percent who can partake. Reality begs to differ. Mass prosperity under U.S. capitalism is gone for good.
Z.Z. cited Gar Alperovitz: "The 'evolutionary reconstructive' approach is a form of change different not only from traditional reform, but different, too, from traditional theories of 'revolution'." Alperovitz made a tactical error of openly denying revolution. Davidson is more sophisticated; he babbles on about socialism and cooperatives, simply ignoring the issue of overthrowng capitalism (except when he lectures that a vote for Obama is a precondition for it).
'Just will and organization?' No, Of course not. There are objective factors as well--deep crises, wars, deadlocked political blocs on top, the need to split ruling parties.
But I stressed the subjective factors of political will and organization, since those are the ones we can most readily do something about. If you're trying to make a case that I'm a reformist or social-dem of some sort, lots of luck. But my main point remains--socialism is a transitional class society, with a different class setting the direction, but getting to the classless society of communism is going to take a long while, especially on a world scale.
(In one sense, since I'm now over 70, I'd love to be proven wrong on this. I'd love to see more of what I've been fighting for all my life before I move on. But if you expect to see it in, say, the next 10 years, would you like to make a friendly wager?)
You can diss MCC as much as you like. No skin off my nose. I've visited and studied there, and find them worthwhile, with all their strengths and a few weaknesses, too. MCC will go on, and it will likely continue to inspire some worthwhile projects here. If you don't care for them, that's your business.
And the socialisms that do exist in this world--China, Cuba and so on, they will continue visiting them and learning some valuable lessons for their own realities.
Post a Comment