The
reason for virtual disappearance of great depressions is the new attitude of
the electorate… [E]conomic science knows how to use monetary and fiscal policy
to keep any recessions that break out from snowballing into lasting chronic
slumps. If Marxians wait for capitalism to collapse in a final crisis, they
wait in vain. We have eaten of the Fruit of the Tree of Knowledge and, for
better or worse, there is no returning to laissez faire capitalism. The
electorate in a mixed economy insists that any political party which is in
power—whether it be the Republican or the Democratic, the Tory or the Labor
party—take the expansionary actions that can prevent depressions. Economics,
8th Addition, Paul Samuelson (1970, McGraw-Hill), p. 250.
Since Samuelson---probably the most
influential bourgeois economist of the post-war era---died at the end of 2009,
we will never know if he would now retract these statements. Every claim in the
above quote is false, and false in a way that sheds light on where we are
today. And because every claim is false,
policy makers are in a hell of a mess.
The reason for virtual
disappearance of great depressions is the new attitude of the electorate…… [E]conomic science knows how to use monetary and fiscal policy to keep
any recessions that break out from snowballing into lasting chronic slumps.
In 1970, when the 8th
edition of Samuelson’s iconic textbook was published, nearly everyone did share
the belief that government had access to tools that could reverse any slump.
Even the old red-baiting Cold Warrior President, Richard Nixon, embraced
Keynesian prescriptions at that time.
But matters changed quickly in the
1970s. A long period of inflation and stagnant growth settled in, seemingly
immune to fiscal and monetary therapy. The loss of the “stimulus” of the war in
Vietnam and a restructuring of energy prices challenged the consensus
celebrated by Samuelson. Many economists identified the soaring inflation with
union and other cost-of-living escalators; consequently, a dampening of wages
and benefits was urged, a tendency that continues unabated today. By the end of
the 1970s, Treasury Secretary Volker’s shock therapy to contain inflation
brought the US economy into deep recession. The Reagan victory in 1980 signaled
a loss of confidence in government intervention and the rise of a competitive
ideology. Some called it “voodoo economics,” but it proved to have amazing
resilience: it turned away from the Keynesian toolbox, and it established a new
consensus.
We have eaten of the Fruit of the Tree
of Knowledge and, for better or worse, there is no returning to laissez faire
capitalism.
By 1980, the “Fruit” was less than
appetizing. Reagan’s election (and Thatcher’s before him) signaled a return to
the gruel of laissez faire under the
cheery brand description, “neo-liberalism.” A whole new set of popular terms
like “supply side,” “trickle down,” etc. were created to sell the new thinking,
while the “deep” thinkers of academia, cast off the economics of aggregates and
the priority of demand for the micro-foundations of Hobbes and his selfish, but
rational animal dominating his/her living space. By 1992, with both the
collapse of European socialism and the election of a “New Democratic”
President, the “Tree of Knowledge” was a mere stump and neo-liberalism had
penetrated nearly every aspect of life in the most advanced capitalist
countries. Laissez faire returned
with a vengeance and enjoyed even greater dominance than in its original
incarnation. And the restored economic doctrine saw no need for the tools of
repair since it saw the capitalist market as self-correcting.
The electorate in a mixed economy
insists that any political party which is in power—whether it be the Republican
or the Democratic, the Tory or the Labor party—take the expansionary actions
that can prevent depressions.
This unassailable truth of 1970 has
proven to not only be assailable, but down right false. The political parties
mentioned by Samuelson – the dominant parties in the US and UK – did not
vigorously defend the value of “expansionary actions;” rather, they fled from
the policy as though it were radioactive. With William Clinton’s ascendancy to
the Presidency at the head of the old New Deal party, advocates of expansionary
government intervention had been largely purged from prominence in the
Democratic Party. Likewise, Tony Blair’s rise to Prime Minister in the UK
signaled the Labour Party’s wholesale embrace of neo-liberalism.
Of course Samuelson’s claim that the
“electorate… insists…” on these policies was never tested because the
electorate was never asked — elites settled the matter for them. In 1970,
prominent intellectuals still believed that important matters were decided
through the electoral process; surely few share that illusion today, when
political actors persistently ignore the will of the electorate on matters like
taxing the rich or shoring up social programs.
It bears reflecting upon the words of
the Nobel committee in awarding the prize in economics to Samuelson in the same
year as the publication of the 8th edition: “More than any other
contemporary economist, Samuelson has helped to raise the general analytical
and methodological level in economic science. He has simply rewritten
considerable parts of economic theory.” Unfortunately,
the “general analytical and methodological level” has proven to be unhelpful in understanding the course of economic history.
If Marxians wait for capitalism to
collapse in a final crisis, they wait in vain.
Samuelson’s peculiar coinage of the
term “Marxians” suggests that he seldom engaged Marxists to solicit their
opinion. Of course one does encounter Marxist-poseurs who frequently and loudly
predict an apocalyptic final collapse of capitalism just as one hears of
half-baked fans who believe the Chicago Cubs will win the World Series—it’s
possible, but not likely.
Capitalism will assuredly disappear as
a result of “a final conflict” (“C’est la lutte finale” in the original words
of the Internationale) and not a
final economic crisis. Yet there is a relationship between economic and social
crises and the final conflict that will push capitalism into the fabled
historic dustbin. That is just to say that wars, economic calumnies, or
political paralysis are almost always the immediate and decisive causes of
revolutionary risings.
We cannot give Samuelson this point,
however, because he meant to deny both that (1) economic crises will not alone
bring down capitalism and that (2) no economic crisis – like the Great
Depression—can again shake the foundations of the capitalist edifice. On the
later, all (authentic) Marxists are in agreement: capitalism cannot, from its
internal logic, escape serious economic turmoil; crises are inescapable
partners of the accumulation process.
With capitalism’s foundations seriously
buffeted by the last four years of bank failures, housing foreclosures, mass
layoffs, financial scandals, shrinking wealth, stagnant incomes, dwindling
social services, and a host of other blows, few would want to stand on the
ground carved out by Samuelson in 1970. What may have appeared to be
transparently obvious in 1970 is now decidedly questionable in the light of the
protracted economic crisis that we have endured since late 2008.
The Next Step?
I have written often and confidently
that we have only seen the first act of a continuing severe structural crisis
of global capitalism. Regardless of policy initiatives, there is much more pain
and economic chaos ahead. Contrary to the most esteemed minds of the economic
profession, there are no quick or decisive solutions to be found from either
the market fundamentalists or the Keynesian heretics opposing them. And their
political expressions—conservative and social democratic parties – are equally
bankrupt, offering no real exit from the looming disaster. Thus, both the
seriously damaged economic engine and impotent political institutions combine
to guarantee that the crisis will be with us for some time to come.
For the moment, Europe is the locus of
the global crisis. The European Union project, realized in an era of great
optimism and capitalist triumphalism, is in imminent danger of collapsing; its
vulnerability to predatory financial capitalism has left its constituent
countries, particularly its weakest countries, in immediate danger of reversion
to nineteenth century standards of development and living. The global market
mechanism has determined that Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Spain and probably
Italy have no essential role in the global economy except for nostalgic tourism
and retirement villas.
The illusion of a unified Europe,
devoid of borders and with a shared standard of living, is just that—an
illusion. The old economic and social relations of dominance and exploitation
did not evaporate in Europe because politicians voted in idyllic times to
create a union. And with a profound global crisis, the weaknesses of this
unsteady union became the target of the bond vultures that turn hardship into
profits. In the beginning, these bond vultures swooped down upon Greece, capturing
its economy for the big banks and handing its sovereignty to the European
imperial centers. I wrote of the weakness and vulnerability of this union often
in 2008 and 2009. I returned to this theme in November, 2011: “one might
conclude that unification – mutually beneficial combinations of national
entities—is extremely unlikely to be successful with capitalist social and
economic relations intact. Conversely, socialist social and economic relations,
linked with an internationalist perspective hold the only real, lasting
opportunity for unity among diverse states.”
The Great Debt Dilemma
The foreclosing of a bourgeois solution
to the European crisis arises from the dominance of finance capital in the
world economy. That is to say, no real solution is available through policy
initiatives crafted by bourgeois economists or advocated by politicians who are
intent upon keeping state-monopoly capitalism unchanged while ignoring the
predatory role of the financial sector. Those who hope to return to the capitalism
of Samuelson’s time are simply delusional.
Market fundamentalists who thought that
the Euro-crisis would dissipate with a bit of budget discipline, a heavy dose
of government austerity, and perhaps a few emergency loans have been thoroughly
discredited by shrinking growth, even greater debt burdens, and intense human
suffering. The wholesale dumping of political incumbents has signaled the
bankruptcy of conservative answers to those ruling elites who first chose this
road.
In the trail of this failure is the “I
told you so” of the Keynesians and social democrats. In truth, liberal
economists were loud and outspoken about policies that hung on a thin strand of
hope rather than rational thought (Despite the fact that policies of austerity
made absolutely no sense, it drove the media and politicians into a frenzy of
advocacy—a tribute to the power of elitist wishful thinking over common sense).
Krugman, Stiglitz and a host of other economists seek to bolster the social
democratic case by advocating robust deficit spending to re-kindle growth in
the Euro-zone. They argued sensibly that austerity and reduced government
spending would only make matters worse. And they assumed that the converse—more
government stimuli—would therefore make matters better. But this is a non sequitur.
Certainly more government spending when directed towards programs that benefit
those suffering from the economic crisis is a justifiable social good and
urgently needed, though it does not follow that it is necessarily a prescription
for recovery. Neither the historical record nor theory demonstrates that
government spending is a sure-fire recipe for restoring capitalist growth and
profitability. It may help, it may not. And it will not in this case unless we
excise the influence of financial markets upon the fate of the Euro-zone.
To hear the social democrats, the
answer to the European debt crisis is to reject austerity in favor of growth.
But they forget or choose to ignore the elephant in the room: the international
debt market. Bond vultures, their accomplices --the credit rating agencies, and
lending institutions-- pounce on even a hint of deficit spending. The entire
contemporary history of the European crisis is that of a crisis engineered by
debt holders who view any additional credit extension or currency deflation as
a threat to their existing debt holdings. And they hold the power to enforce
their interests through debt markets. Equally, they have nearly all the
European political forces in a strangle hold that places the interests of the
financial sector ahead of all else. That is the demonstrated dominance of
finance capital in the twenty-first century. We ignore this at our peril.
The facile answer of the social
democrats—from the recent successful electoral campaign of the “socialists” in
France to the ascendancy of SYRIZA in Greece—is to reject austerity and endorse
growth. But this is no answer at all if it depends upon the “good will” of
financial markets that neither have a “will” nor respect the social “good.” The
dominance of finance capital cannot be wished or negotiated away.
Nor is exit from the Euro an option
without a radical break from international finance. Credit markets will be
closed to any country that departs the zone without guaranteeing the integrity of
existing debt, a burden that leaves an exiting or exiled country exactly where
it was before it left.
Doom
or Promise?
The debt dilemma poses an impossible
challenge to those who wish to see Europe governed as usual. It forecloses both
a conservative and social democratic answer to the current crisis ravaging
Europe. Understandably, the habits of decades of complacency and relative
stability leave the electorate with a desire to find an easy way out within the
confines of the known rather than a leap into the unknown. Embracing solutions
beyond the habitual ones comes with great difficulty even among the victims.
But for four years, the habitual solutions have failed and the debt dilemma
gives us every reason to believe that they will continue to fail.
Only a vigorous people’s movement
determined to overthrow the dominance of finance capital will lead Europe (and
the rest of us) out of the death grip of financial markets. Central to that
overthrow is the establishment of public ownership and control over financial
institutions and the removal of those institutions from the market place. It is
a nascent movement; we see its stirrings in the growth of the Communist
movement emerging around the ideological pole established by the Greek
Communist Party, a Party that refuses to compromise by joining a doomed-to-fail
coalition government with no answer to the debt dilemma. The era of smug,
smooth, and easy recoveries from the capitalist business cycle, as announced by
Paul Samuelson, is over. Likewise, the era of economic tinkering and political
self-satisfaction is inadequate for this moment. We enter a new era with fear
and uncertainty gripping most of the world’s population. Therefore, the
realization of the promise of the new era may be a while in coming, but it's
surely coming.
Zoltan Zigedy
zoltanzigedy@gmail.com
2 comments:
great article as always comrade, once again social democrats are getting carried away with Holland and Syriza. Just like they did with Obama. will they ever learn is not even the right question cos they dont want to learn such is their anti-socialism
In all fairness to Samuelson, he is not entirely mistaken in observing that the ruling class "have eaten from Fruit of the Tree of Knowledge." Bernanke had learned the lessons of the Great Depression and used his knowledge to stave off a deflationary spiral. Same in politics. The capitalist state has learned well the hard lessons of the 20th century. No more frolicking with socialist, anti-System ideas is allowed in the public sphere of bourgeois society. It's hard to believe that in the past, works like Marx's "18th Brumaire" were published on the front pages of leading bourgeois newspapers. The Bolshevik revolution in Russia that promised the coming withering of the state had led to opposite results. Hobbes' Leviathan seems puny in comparison , with the tremendous machines of terror, coercion, and all-pervading control in the hands of the modern state, from the USSR and Third Reich to "Western democracies." The exploited classes have also learned from history. But this knowledge is not helpful to them, because it's a knowledge of failure and because it's controlled by the capitalist state. Thus the historical imagination of workers, even politically active workers, no longer transcends the fundamental arrangements of the capitalist system of production.
Post a Comment